logo

37 pages 1 hour read

A Short History of Progress

Nonfiction | Book | Adult | Published in 2004

A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.

Chapter 4Chapter Summaries & Analyses

Chapter 4 Summary: “Pyramid Schemes”

The “two most famous cases of internal collapse” (82) of empires are Rome, circa fourth century AD, and the Mayans, circa ninth century AD. As empires, both these cultures behave like pyramid schemes: “they gather wealth to the centre from an expanding periphery, which may be the frontier of a political and trading empire or a colonization of nature” (83-4). This expansive use of human and natural resources has the effect of destabilizing these cultures exactly as they reach their peak.

Like the Sumerians, deforestation impacted the peoples of the Mediterranean, which they carried out by the sixth century BC to provide goats grazing room. Though the Greeks saw this happening and tried to work against it, the ecological damage they had done to the region’s water system contributed to the wane of their cultural power in the region by 400 BC. Power shifted to Rome, which itself had to become reliant on foreign grain to survive this resource drought.

By the fourth century AD Rome controlled around 50 million people, roughly 25 percent of the human race. Roman conquest had become a private industry, with soldiers able to reap the rewards of conquered regions. As the military class grew in wealth, public land in Rome, including farmsteads, passed into the power of large estates established by wealthy military personnel. This forced Rome to become an analogue of a modern welfare state, providing free grain to an extensive population that could not feed itself. In fact, “By the time of Claudius, 200,000 Roman families were on the dole” (90).

Rome’s history is that of a transformation from a Republic into an Empire.  When Emperor Augustus (63 BC-19 AD) consolidated the Roman borders, he allowed the capital to “grow long after its dominions had begun to fray at the edges” (91). By the end of its reign, Rome was facing many problems that contributed to its collapse, including rampant inflation, tax exemption for wealthy land-owners, and poor agricultural yields. As the arable land of Rome continued to erode “Rome exported its environmental load to the colonies, becoming dependent on grain from North Africa and the Middle East” (93). Depleting these landscapes as well, Rome collapsed at its core, with power shifting to the peripheral regions of the empires. The boom of Roman population would not be seen again until the modern day.

The Chavin civilization, ancestors of the Maya, spread over much of Peru throughout the first millennium BC. During the Roman empire, their largest city, Teotihuacan, rivalled the size of Rome itself. Widespread civilization in Mesoamerica, in fact, emerged around 1200 BC. Around 200 AD the Mayan Classical Period began, though the civilization had been thriving long before.

Today the Mayan temples are surrounded by jungle, but this was farmland during the Mayan era. The Mayans were highly advanced in their use of mathematics and writing, and they developed a precise calendrical system known as the Long Count based on “the most accurate astronomy until Europe’s Renaissance” (96). The Maya were also highly agriculturally productive, using canals in swamps to control water to crops. They created “A familiar social pyramid arose” (97) supported by agricultural growth due to increased deforestation. This deforestation accompanied game loss and “by the middle of the Classic Period, only the upper class was eating much meat” (98). As resources shrank, elite power was destabilized, and the civilization collapsed by the year 909 AD mostly due to unsustainable population growth and agrarian failure. Bone remains show malnourishment of the peasants during times of growth, and that even the health of elites declined during the final years of the empire. Evidence suggests that, like the people of Easter Island, the Mayan elites did not shift their political strategies as their civilization neared collapse, but “dug in their heels […] their solution was higher pyramids […] more power to the kings” (102). To use a contemporary comparison, “the Maya elite became extremist, or ultra-conservatives, squeezing the last drops of profit from nature and humanity” (102).

Not all ancient civilizations share the exact same trajectory of collapse as Easter Island, Sumer, Rome, or the Maya. Egypt, for example, sustained its civilization for 3000 consecutive years. How? Silt from the Nile refreshed soils every year, and the desert around the region provided a natural border to arable land that the people could not expand. Conservative farming and slow population growth enforced by famine in dry years allowed Egypt to live within its ecological means. In China, fertile land was hundreds of feet deep due to ancient deposits of glacial topsoil, and so “this land was almost endlessly forgiving [to agriculture and deforestation], with erosion merely exposing new layers of good earth” (104). Even these cultures, who still faced the problems of civil unrest and fallow years, show that the overall health of a civilization is dependent on the health of its land, water, and woods.

Chapter 4 Analysis

In “Pyramid Schemes” Wright extends his history of societal progress and its subsequent collapse beyond that of individual city-states into that of empires, cultural networks that stretch over continents. In doing so, Wright shows how intertwined trends in ecological and social dominance, as seen in the last chapter, progress with history. Wright suggests that the natural tendency of human progress, should it survive long enough, is toward empires, but that these empires have the same essential problems of lesser cultures, just at a grander scale.

To describe the dual social and ecological dominance that defines all civilizations, and with the advent of geographical expansiveness that also defines empires, Wright selects the symbol of the pyramid. His reasons for selecting this specific symbol are two-fold: first, the symbol of the pyramid articulates “the outward and visible sign of a human social pyramid” (83), i.e. a top-down hierarchy from the few to the many. Secondarily, the social pyramid is analogous to and “carried by a less visible natural pyramid—the food chain and all other resources in the surrounding ecology” (83). It is no mistake, Wright implies, that monuments of such structure are found throughout human history—not only in Egypt, but also Babylon and Maya. Indeed “colossal statues, tombs, or office towers” (83) are in some sense pyramids, symbols of human resource wealth and hierarchy. The pyramid, Wright implies, is the continuation of the Easter Island head, with all its cultural connotations of prestige and its historical connections to excess.

Rome provides the chapter’s first history of a pyramid scheme. It can also be thought to straddle an important historical divide in the text. Rome is both a civilization of the ancient world and, with Greece, an important model of the modern West, at least since the Renaissance. Wright plays with this aspect of the history of Rome, acknowledging how Rome’s trajectory from Republic to Empire resembles modern countries, “including both Canada and the United States” (90). He also, however, highlights Rome’s low life expectancy and uncleanliness due to lack of industrial water transport. Reminding that the Roman government suffered from problems of tax exemption and inflation, recalling modern issues, he subverts cultural elitism in the West’s attachment to Rome. The story remains, however, one of the closest historical analogues to today’s own cultures and serves to illustrate how little modern problems differ from those that brought down the great historical cultures.

When Wright begins to discuss the Mayan empire, he emphasizes its contemporaneity with Rome and survival past it. The Mayans lived in cities that “rivalled the scale of Rome” (95) and thrived on man-made agrarian landscapes that Wright must remind the reader are not the jungles we see around their temples today. Furthermore, they created advanced calendrical and astronomical systems. These aspects of Mayan history remind the reader to decentralize their historical vision away from Western civilization to understand a full picture of human history. Furthermore, it recontextualizes our idea of indigenous cultures as necessarily primitive. Wright’s comparison of the Mayan elite to conservative industrialists draws a parallel between this culture and ours that again reminds of our own historical unexceptionally at the same time as it destabilizes Eurocentric ideals.

Holding two cultures from different hemispheres but similar historical periods together in a single chapter reminds the reader not only of the equality of cultural progress, but the equality of decline. Though both these cultures were once great empires whose monuments survive in the form of Coliseums in Rome and stepped temples in Mesoamerica, their final years were characterized by the same decline and destruction. The concept that all the cultures of the world are destined to rise and fall is neatly summed up earlier in the chapter when Wright  provides a litany of the empires the sun touches in a single day (85). Just as the sun rose on all these gleaming cultures, all with their own pyramids, it has since set on them.

blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
Unlock IconUnlock all 37 pages of this Study Guide

Plus, gain access to 8,800+ more expert-written Study Guides.

Including features:

+ Mobile App
+ Printable PDF
+ Literary AI Tools